Cover Page

To J.-C. L.

Smart Innovation Set

coordinated by
Dimitri Uzunidis

Volume 13

Enterprise Knowledge Capital

Blandine Laperche

image

Acknowledgements

This book is based on the academic work I have conducted over the course of many years, often accompanied by colleagues who have also been my friends and companions on this journey. They are sources of inspiration and the wonderful co-authors of articles, chapters, books and reports, which have fed my thinking and which can often be found within the text presented here in this book.

I would therefore like to thank them warmly in alphabetical order: Sophie Boutillier, Arnaud Diemer, Delphine Gallaud, Claudine Gay, Alfredo Ilardi, Denis Langlet, Gilliane Lefebvre, Zeting Liu, Fabienne Picard, Dimitri Uzunidis and Nejla Yacoub. I would also like to take this opportunity to thank those with whom I co-edited books on related topics and who have not been cited previously, in particular Djellal Faridah, Faïz Gallouj, Joëlle Forest, James K. Galbraith, Nadine Levratto, Sophie Reboud, Paul Sommers, Corinne Tanguy, Leila Temri and Nick Von Tunzelmann. I would also like to address my thanks to Philippe Chagnon for his essential support with the technical realization of the diagrams and Brent Ryan Barber for his great help with the publication of the english version of this book. Daniele Archibugi has done me the honor of writing the foreword of this book, may he receive a testimony of my gratitude.

Finally, my thanks go naturally and very sincerely to Dimitri Uzunidis, the author of this book’s postface, the person who has guided and accompanied me in my research for many years, for the many exciting discussions that never fail to animate us and the development of ever more absorbing projects with the Research Network on Innovation, which he chairs. I count myself as so lucky to have met and be surrounded by such incredible people, who are continuously expanding the scope of what is possible. I am very grateful.

The publication of this book has received the support of Bpifrance Le Lab. I warmly thank Frédérique Savel and Elise Tissier.

image

Foreword

In a film that is already 20 years old, New Rose Hotel, Abel Ferrara described a society in which large corporations dominate the world. They have money, power and, above all, competences to do it. The key element for their success is knowledge and they fiercely compete among each other to generate innovation-based new products. New knowledge is still generated by humans rather than by machines, and therefore bright scientists and engineers are the strategic resources for companies’ prosperity. Corporations rightly assume that very creative individuals are likely to generate several good ideas in their life – the very gooses that lay golden eggs. The film describes the attempt of one corporation to “steal” the most creative scientist, the genius of the time, for the competing company. The scientist is already very well paid, and is unlikely to be attracted by a greater salary. Here starts the thrill: will the gangsters hired by the company manage to persuade a spectacularly successful scientist to abandon his corporation and to join the competitor? Will they manage to get his brain by conquering his heart?

The film addresses several issues that are essential in the knowledge economy. First, is it true that top scientists and engineers are the core strategic asset of modern corporations? So far, this is far from being the case. Those who work in the R&D departments are unlikely to be the better-paid employees of a company. Most of the chief executive officers of large corporations originated from the financial sector or marketing, under the assumption that being good at managing money and selling products is more important than generating exciting new products and processes. But in the future this is less likely to occur and the progress of the knowledge economy will give more weight to those who are scientifically and technically competent rather than to those who command the tricks of the stock markets or of advertising.

Second, are some individuals so creative that they generate several fundamental discoveries and inventions in their working lifespan? This is already the case and we know that a few creative people are able to generate a wealth of great ideas. Bach, Mozart and Beethoven have composed dozens of masterpieces and this is not an exception. The statistics on the authorship of scientific articles and patents do show that a very few scientists and engineers are responsible for delivering the large majority of high-impact results. It is therefore understandable that corporations try to secure the best minds and head-hunting is already a common practice of oligopolistic competition. It is very likely that we see head-hunters more often around the areas where creativity is a must such as R&D, software development and design. It might appear that the film underestimates the importance of teams and gives too much credit to individual geniuses, but a surprise hidden in the finale shows that networks of good inventors can be economically more important than a single top scientist.

Third, the film challenges the traditional view that the most important incentive to stimulate very creative people is financial. Of course, we know that incentives are crucial to secure the talent of the most gifted. In football, the transfer of top players from one team to another is dominated by the salaries paid, but perhaps those who have their talent in their heads, rather than in their feet, are likely to be more sophisticated and to praise other aspects of life as well as money. Not only scientists working in universities and public research centers, but also their colleagues employed in the business sector give high importance to the intellectual environment in which they operate, the freedom they enjoy in pursuing their agendas, the possibility to discuss ideas with colleagues as well as real or potential competitors.

Twenty years ago, a few spectators were persuaded that knowledge would become the crucial competitive asset for companies. Today, only a few will dispute it. But for those who still have some doubts, this book, elegantly written by Blandine Laperche, will provide definitively convincing arguments. This book clearly explains how the knowledge capital of companies is constructed and how it provides benefits to companies as well as to society at large. Three issues are crucial to Blandine Laperche’s enquiry.

The first is the definition of innovation. For several decades, the Schumpeterian tradition has argued that innovating firms bring dynamism to the economy and are able to generate profits, efficiency and employment through the introduction of new products and processes. Innovating firms have unanimously been considered the frontrunners of progress and prosperity. But the specific understanding of innovation has too often been too narrow. Implicitly more than explicitly, we have assumed that innovation should be understood as something “technological” that is introduced in the “manufacturing” industries. True, for many decades the manufacturing industry provided a wealth of new products and processes that were used and diffused in agriculture as well as in the services. Still, it is too limited to presume that the production of innovation is confined to manufacturing and that the other industries are just users. In a world where the largest share of employment and value added comes from services, this traditional approach needs to be radically revised. We need to understand that innovation occurs in a much broader context; otherwise, we will not be able to understand why some that do not belong to the manufacturing industry are among the more prolific generators of fresh ideas and patents. Take the case of IBM, a company with more than a century on its shoulders, or the much younger Google: both are world leading innovators outside the realm of the manufacturing industry. Are we ready to take the challenge on board and to revise our toolkit? This book faithfully reports the state of the art: we can be happy for the progress achieved in the last decades producing broader and more comprehensive concepts and measures of innovation, but it clearly emerges that much still needs to be done to have instruments able to guide public policies and business strategies.

The second issue is the strong belief that the successful creation of knowledge capital by firms is rooted in a much wider economic and social space. Blandine Laperche builds upon the literature on national innovation systems to give a proper role to the relations between public and business players in augmenting the stock of knowledge. She shows that knowledge-based corporations do not work in a vacuum but rather in a heavily populated space where they interact with governments, universities, research centers, users and competitors. Her insights derive from an older and glorious academic tradition, the French historical École des Annales, which long before the economics of innovation became a popular subject, already understood the crucial role played by complex interactions between social institutions and techniques. In describing the boundaries of the firm, Blandine also takes into account how they have been transformed by the Internet revolution. The open innovation model, one of the most popular developments in the field, has penetrated large and small firms differently and this has relevant consequences for business strategies. The implication is that all companies could potentially take advantage of the existing opportunities, but if they fail to do it, it is likely that they will be marginalized.

The third issue is the way in which corporations are opening to the global society. The knowledge capital developed by companies is not sufficient by itself to sustain economic performance. It should also be properly protected against real and potential competitors in internal and, above all, global markets. But the boundaries of intellectual property right are highly uncertain: as with any property rights, intellectual property is guaranteed, protected and enforced by national governments. In spite of the harmonization that has taken place over the years and, most notably, since the foundation of the World Trade Organization in 1995, each nation still has its own rules and practices. Companies’ strategies are therefore forced to operate in uncharted waters and the attempt made in this book to map them is precious. The potential of companies to defend their own knowledge in isolation is more and more blurred. Blandine suggests that a really successful innovative company should not be obsessed with the protection of its knowledge, but rather it should be willing to share it because they know that this is the best way to move up in the learning curve. To put its own knowledge into a common pool is often the best way for a corporation to provide the standard to everybody. This is a lesson that perhaps several governments, obsessed with the protection of the intellectual property belonging to their own nations, have not yet properly assimilated.

The main lesson to be drawn from this dense, well-written and well-informed volume is that knowledge-based firms are not just profit-maximizing machines but rather institutions embedded into a much wider social fabric. In spite of the several attempts made to create fences around its fruits, knowledge will continue to provide benefits to a larger community of users. Marc Bloch already taught this in the 1930s with his seminal investigation of the Medieval watermills and Bertrand Gille in the 1970s with his comprehensive Histoire des techniques. We should be grateful to Blandine Laperche and her colleagues at the Research Network on Innovation for developing these ancient insights to better understand the knowledge-based company of the 21st Century.

Daniele ARCHIBUGI
Professor of Economics

Introduction

“Every civilization” writes Braudel “imports and exports aspects of its culture. These may include the lost-wax process for casting, the compass, gunpowder, the technique for tempering steel, a complete or fragmentary philosophical system, a cult, a religion or the song about Marlborough that went the rounds of Europe in the eighteenth century: Goethe heard it in the streets of Verona in 1786…” (p. 14). He continues on to say that “civilizations continually borrow from their neighbors, even if they ‘reinterpret’ and assimilate what they have adopted. At first sight, indeed, every civilization looks rather like a railway goods yard, constantly receiving and dispatching miscellaneous deliveries” (p. 29) (Braudel [BRA 93]).

Innovation today is at the heart of business strategy: it is associated with adaptation, change, rebirth, recovery, competitiveness and growth. It is embellished with qualifying adjectives intended to make it even more original: innovation today is disruptive (Christensen [CHR 97]), open (Chesbrough [CHE 03]), frugal (Radjou et al. [RAD 12]), reversed (Govindarajan and Trimble [GOV 12]), fractal (Midler et al. [MID 17]), etc. Technological, organizational and commercial innovation is thus an inevitable trajectory, which can even be considered, for both small and large companies alike, as an injunction carrying with it the penalty of going under in the face of the continuous and globalized tide of competition. But how does a company innovate? What activities become intertwined once the black box of innovation has been opened? How does a company decide what the necessary collaboration with other actors should be in order to succeed in its innovation process and, equally fundamental, what protection it needs to implement in order to secure these achievements and cement their dominant position within their networks?

The purpose of this book is to study the strategies and processes of innovation through the prism of knowledge capital. Here, we define knowledge capital as the set of scientific and technical information and knowledge produced, acquired, combined and systematized by one or more companies within a particular productive objective, and more broadly, within a process of value creation. Knowledge capital therefore refers to the knowledge accumulated by a company, which often maintains collaborations with other companies or institutions for this purpose. It is integrated into the individuals, machines, technologies and routines of a company. It is constantly enriched by the flow of information. It is used to create or improve upon existing products and services, but it can also become an intangible product to be transferred to other economic actors. Knowledge capital is therefore a dynamic concept, a process that describes accumulated knowledge, its enrichment, its combinations and the various forms of its use. This associated objective of value creation is the main condition for transforming knowledge into capital.

Understanding the meaning of knowledge capital requires a return to the key terms and central concepts that structure it. Therefore, Chapter 1 shall revisit the definition of innovation, its evolution over time, but also the processes, that is the organization of activities, that give rise to it. It will also recall the difficulties in assessing innovation. We shall set out to dissect the words knowledge and information, showing how they differ and how they complement each other in order to organize our approach to knowledge capital. We shall also detail its roles, both productive and organizational, within the broader process of value creation. Our definition of knowledge capital is based on the theoretical developments of three key concepts: firm, knowledge and capital. A brief review of contemporary theories of the firm allows us to grasp the advancements being made in the analysis of knowledge production activities within organizations. However, the re-reading of a few founding authors is also essential for a better understanding of the dynamics for the production, use and appropriation of knowledge capital.

Chapter 2 positions knowledge capital in terms of its historical context: industrial capitalism. The rapprochement between science and technology, which is essential to the formation of knowledge capital, is an old one, but has been advanced largely through the impulse of industrial needs, all the way from the manufacturer to the large-scale industry (Gille [GIL 78]). Teams or worker collectives are formed, combine skills and facilitate their appropriation in order to accelerate value production (Marx [MAR 67]). We trace this history and expound upon the reasons and forms of this rapprochement that culminated at the end of the 19th Century in the systematic relationship between science and technology (Habermas [HAB 68]), orchestrated by the States and the gradual creation of national innovation systems (Freeman [FRE 87]), (Lundvall [LUN 92]). This chapter presents the organizational changes in large enterprises in the 20th Century and the emergence of the various forms of organizational networks. The modern network firm model allows for multiple collaborations that are implemented (through open innovation) in order to collectively build knowledge capital (Laperche and Uzunidis [LAP 18]). In this chapter, we study the ways in which large companies create their knowledge capital by drawing on internal resources (accumulated skills, research and development expenditures) and external resources developed together with other companies, both large and small, as competitors or as partners, with institutions of academic research but also directly with consumers. The case of small companies is also analyzed, emphasizing their greatest difficulties, particularly in France, to independently capitalize on their knowledge capital, that is to say without integrating into existing networks formed and dominated by larger firms. This chapter therefore points to the increasing socialization of knowledge capital, which means that an increasing number of all kinds of companies and institutions contribute to the enrichment of the knowledge capital of each firm. At the forefront of these institutions are universities and public research centers. The third mission, which has been assigned to these institutions since the end of the 20th Century, that of the commercialization of research, is part of this desire/need to support the enrichment of the knowledge capital of firms.

Furthermore, this enrichment of knowledge capital is also reflected in the constant expansion of scientific and technical networks at the global scale (Archibugi and Filippetti [ARC 15]). This topic is the subject of Chapter 3. The multinational corporations of yesteryear have since become global and today weave their webs at the scale of the whole planet. Certainly, as Fernand Braudel emphasized in the words quoted above, cultural, scientific and technical goods have always had the peculiarity of being mobile. Yet, up until the end of the 20th Century, business research and development (R&D) activities were most often locked safely within the borders of the multinational companies’ home country. However, R&D has gradually become more internationalized as value chains have become more globalized. R&D laboratories were first established in other Triad countries and today are also based in the ultra-sophisticated clusters of emerging countries. Strategic alliances connect the scientific and technological centers of the planet (Narula, Martinez-Noya [NAR 15]). Reasons for this phenomenon of R&D globalization are to be found in the liberalization of markets (goods and services, labor, financial), which makes this globalization of R&D not only possible but flexible. The reasons are also related to the climate of trust that ensues from the globalization of intellectual property rights (IPRs), which ideally ensures the protection of the scientific and technological resources being propagated worldwide. Above all, the globalization of R&D is mainly driven by the profitability imperative that induces enterprises to reduce production costs, and absorb any new creative source or any new commercial opportunity, wherever it emerges in the world. This need for profitability stems from the weighting of finance in the strategy of companies, with shareholders demanding substantial returns on their investment (shareholder value). Financial globalization, an advanced feature of commercial and productive globalization, plays a key role in business strategies and the structuring of our knowledge-based societies (Chesnais [CHE 96], Laperche and Uzunidis [LAP 08]). It also plays a role in the strategies for the appropriation of knowledge capital, which are becoming increasingly aggressive the more that knowledge capital becomes socialized.

Indeed, this chapter also devotes focus to the important strategic developments of the appropriation of knowledge capital as it is deployed by companies. IPRs are controversial, as they are coupled with traditional roles of protection and incentives to innovate, as well as with barriers to entry (Boldrin and Levine [BOL 08]). We look at these contradictory roles from two angles, that of the multi-partner relationship and that of the extension of IPRs at the international scale, and into new fields. In the context of multi-partner innovation strategies, IPRs acquire a central coordination role, helping to legitimize their existence and even their profusion within knowledge markets. Nevertheless, opportunistic strategies are present at all stages of cooperation, thereby highlighting the role of IPRs in the creation and structuring of networks. They make it possible to draw a hierarchy between, on the one hand, those who appropriate rents in order to strengthen their dominant position and, on the other hand, other actors, resource suppliers, or prospective participants, who are blocked or in a situation of dependency. Geographical expansion through the agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS, 1994) has the concurrent aim of accelerating the transfer of technology to countries with less scientific and technological resources with the view to stimulating their ability to innovate. Similarly, expansion into new areas (ICT, living organisms, etc.) aims to stimulate innovation in auspicious sectors. Again there are many contradictions. These are revealed, for example, in the costs associated with newly protected technologies, which slow down their dissemination in emerging countries, and the multiple patent wars that, in the field of ICTs in particular, fill the pages of our newspapers. More generally, these contradictions reveal the poor knowledge on the mechanisms by which innovation emerges and spreads.

This book therefore deals with a series of themes, themselves the subject of very detailed, but also relatively fragmented study, within the fields of economics and the management of innovation. Some authors devote their entire careers to the analysis of, for example, open innovation strategies, research commercialization policies, international strategic alliances and/or the use of IPRs. Their work is fundamental because such expertise makes it possible to identify new strategic enhancements, such as how to exploit a particular tool, etc. Nevertheless, it should be noted that there are inherent risks to a fragmented analysis, in the event that it overlooks any links with other similar phenomena, or in terms of their scopes or implications at a broader level. Adopting a systemic approach, and following the thought of Blaise Pascal, who affirmed that “I hold that it is impossible to know the parts without knowing the whole as it is to know the whole without detailed knowledge of the parts”, our goal was to assemble the pieces of the puzzle to reveal a general framework for analysis. It seems to us that this is essential to reach a deeper understanding of the role and meaning for each piece of the puzzle. It reveals two strong and contradictory tendencies: on the one hand, a growing socialization in terms of the production of knowledge capital, and on the other hand, the offensive strategies of appropriation of the value it produces. The understanding of these two parallel and contradictory phenomena is, to our view, really useful in any reflection on innovation. What is the ultimate goal of innovation? Is it contributing more and more to the profit creation of a few dominant companies, or is it responding to the major challenges facing our societies? We believe that these two objectives rarely intersect.

To conclude, this book naturally has its limits. The literature on these themes is so abundant that other developments certainly could have been included. That being said, it should be noted that rather than seeking to provide definitive answers to the questions posed above, this work is part of a desire to stimulate reflection and debate, while at the same time providing key understandings of the issues surrounding the topic that is innovation.